Financial Transaction Control Framework (HTML)
Updated 1 April 2025
1. Overview and scope of this framework
Overview
At Autumn Budget 2024, the government announced reforms to its fiscal framework. The fiscal rules include the investment rule – to reduce debt, defined as public sector net financial liabilities (PSNFL) or net financial debt, as a share of the economy. This is a comprehensive metric that captures all financial assets and liabilities on the public sector balance sheet, as defined in line with international guidance.[footnote 1]
Economic growth is the government’s central mission and well-directed public investment can catalyse private investment. A move to net financial debt recognises where equity investments or loans create financial assets corresponding to the liability incurred to finance them, providing opportunities for government to make financial investments that support growth while generating a return for the Exchequer.
Government must also invest responsibly and the move to target net financial debt is accompanied by controls on financial transactions (FTs), where the public sector acquires or sells financial assets. This framework will ensure that government’s use of FTs is fiscally sustainable and does not cause debt to rise over time.
This document builds on spending controls for managing FTs set out in Managing Public Money (MPM) and Consolidated Budgeting Guidance (CBG).[footnote 2] It does not change budgeting rules set out in CBG, but it does provide guidance on how they are applied in some cases.
The Treasury will only approve spending on FTs where robust controls are in place in line with this framework and it will review the processes of public financial institutions to ensure this.
Structure of this document
The controls set out in this framework are:
-
Guidance on when FTs are an appropriate form of policy intervention and key considerations in designing FTs (Chapter 2).
-
Delivery of new, large-scale FTs through designated public financial institutions with suitable expertise and capability (Chapter 3).
-
Measures to help manage risk and return, including an annual report on government’s financial investment portfolio to provide transparency; requirements around rate of return for FTs; and controls to manage risk of unexpected losses in downside scenarios (Chapter 4).
-
New criteria and approval process for Treasury consent of FTs and decisions on FT budget allocations (Chapter 5).
Spending control of FTs
As set out in budgeting rules and MPM, Treasury consent and budget cover is needed for departments to issue any FTs.
Treasury consent
Departments must have Treasury consent before undertaking spending on FTs or making commitments that could lead to spending on FTs. In line with other spending, Treasury consent is provided by:
-
Delegated limits, below which consent for spending on FTs is delegated to the department; or
-
Direct approval in advance, required for all FTs with an overall value above a department’s delegated limit, or for FTs which are novel, contentious, or repercussive.
Parliament must also approve spending on central government FTs via the estimates process. Budget cover for FTs is reflected in Capital Delegated Expenditure Limit (CDEL) or Capital Annually Managed Expenditure (CAME) control totals and FTs score against these budgets in line with CBG.
Departments will need appropriate legislative powers (vires) to deliver FTs where they constitute a ‘new service’, as set out in MPM.
Spending review and budget processes
Budget cover for FTs managed in DEL is allocated via regular Spending Reviews and budget cover for FTs managed in AME is forecast and reviewed at Budgets.
FTs impact departments’ capital budgets when entered (i.e., when undertaking net lending and the purchase of shares) and as they are exited (e.g., sale of shares).
FTs impact departments’ resource budgets in Resource DEL (RDEL) or Resource AME (RAME) via the returns received on assets, for example, interest received on loans. FTs also impact departments’ resource budgets through changes in asset value and recognition of losses, such as scoring allowances for expected credit losses.
As FTs have distinct fiscal treatment, they form a ringfence within CDEL and CAME budgets. Departments may not switch budget cover out of their FT ringfence without approval from the Treasury.
Enhanced controls for FTs
The government has established the following principles through the Financial Transaction Control Framework (this document). These principles support the government to invest responsibly.
Policy rationale
Government should intervene in the economy to achieve clear policy objectives such as solving market failures and delivering public services. This remains the case for FTs. Where FTs solve market failures in the provision of capital, they can generate a net return for the taxpayer; where they are used to provide subsidies, they are unlikely to do so and are more akin to conventional spending but can represent better value for money than grants.
Government will trade-off costs of FTs with other spending. If government makes investments that generate a return below its cost of borrowing, this worsens the current budget balance and net financial debt over time. The expected costs of FTs will be reflected in the OBR’s forecast and decrease other spending that government can deliver within its fiscal rules. Trading off these costs with other spending will ensure that debt as a share of the economy continues to fall over time.
Public financial institutions
Large-scale, higher risk or complex FTs and guarantees should be delivered by designated public financial institutions, absent Treasury agreement to do otherwise. UK Government Investments can advise departments in assessing riskiness and complexity of new FTs.
Risk and return
FTs should either generate a return above government’s cost of borrowing or recognise costs transparently where FTs are intentionally designed not to do so from the outset. Some losses occur in any portfolio, so rates of return should be considered at the level of portfolio of FTs, not each investment. In various cases, there can be a need to address a market failure by issuing FTs that government expects, at the outset, to be loss-making (i.e., generate a return below government’s cost of borrowing). These costs should be transparently recognised in line with departments’ financial reporting framework.
The government will publish an annual report on central government’s financial investments, delivered by UK Government Investments (UKGI). This report will use asset valuations drawn from government accounts already audited by the National Audit Office (NAO) and other relevant unaudited information. The Treasury is working with the Comptroller and Auditor General to ensure that the report builds appropriately on existing audits of asset valuations, where used. The report will provide transparency to the public and parliament on the value, risk, and performance of government’s financial assets.
New risk-based controls for FTs and guarantees will be introduced. This will be implemented via an economic capital-based approach as is already used in several public financial institutions.
Approval process
The standard information departments must provide for Treasury approval of FTs is set out in Annex E. These flow from the Green Book, with this document covering FT-specific considerations.[footnote 3]
Scope of this framework
Organisations covered
As with CBG, this framework applies to all entities classified by the Office for National Statistics (ONS) to central government, including government departments and their arm’s length bodies. It also applies to any entity designated as a public financial institution in line with Chapter 3 of this framework.
This framework does not apply to the devolved governments as their funding arrangements are set out in the Statement of Funding Policy.[footnote 4] The government is supportive of the devolved governments’ ongoing use of FTs and will continue to engage with them on any impact from the implementation of this framework.
Financial assets and instruments covered
The table below sets out the financial instruments covered by this framework. Definitions follow the National Accounts (SNA 2008 and ESA 2010) statistical frameworks, rather than International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS) based definitions.[footnote 5] FTs are recognised in the National Accounts when financial assets or liabilities are exchanged between the public sector and the private sector or rest of the world.
Table 1.1 Financial assets and instruments
Category | Definition based on the National Accounts |
---|---|
Loan assets | Financial instruments, which must be interest-bearing and have to be repaid at maturity. |
Equity assets | Residual claims held on the assets of private sector corporations through shareholdings or ownership. |
Derivative assets | Financial instruments linked to financial or non-financial assets or to an index, where the value is derived from the underlying asset or index. |
Debt securities assets | Financial instruments like corporate bonds and bills that pay interest and have fixed dates of maturity. |
Financial instruments in partial scope
Student loans are partitioned under National Accounts guidance into a loan (i.e., an FT) component and a capital transfer component. The partition is consistent with the approach taken to other FTs in this document, as it clearly identifies the element of the student loan book that government expects to be repaid (classified as an FT) and the element that is loss-making (classified as a capital transfer).
Guarantees are only in scope of this framework in respect of the requirement for large financial instruments to be delivered by public financial institutions and their inclusion in economic capital limits for public financial institutions, set out in detail in Chapter 4. Wider policy on guarantees and insurance, including their design and approval, is covered by the separate Contingent Liability Approval Framework.[footnote 6]
Loans or equity investments within the public sector may be recognised as FTs from a departmental budgeting perspective where they are transactions with an entity outside the departmental group boundary. However, from a National Accounts perspective, transactions between two parts of the public sector will consolidate out, with no financial asset recognised. In general, they are not in scope of this framework, but where intra-public sector FTs are managed by public financial institutions, they are in scope of the controls in Chapter 3.
Financial assets and instruments not in scope
Assets treated as liquid in UK public finance statistics, such as cash and short-term deposits, are not subject to this framework.[footnote 7]
Grants or loans which require repayment only if certain conditions are met are unlikely to be recognised as financial assets in the National Accounts on issuance until they are transformed into loan or equity assets when a condition is met. They are treated as capital spending and not subject to this framework.
Departments should engage their Treasury spending team to seek guidance on the classification of specific transactions.
2. When should government use financial transactions?
Overview
This chapter sets out guidance for appraising whether an FT (an individual FT, FT programme, or use of the capacity of a public financial institution) is an appropriate tool to achieve government objectives.
It should be read as a set of FT-specific considerations that are supplementary to central guidance for appraisal of government policies, programmes, and projects set out in the Green Book.
This guidance is designed to apply to departments, public financial institutions and any other government organisation delivering an FT. As public financial institutions have been set up to be operationally independent subject to their mandate and financial framework, they will also autonomously identify, design, and deliver FTs.
What should government consider when deciding to use an FT?
Addressing market failures and ensuring additionality
As with all government interventions, the use of FTs must be underpinned by a clear rationale for intervention in line with principles set out in the Green Book, therefore supporting government objectives by delivering outcomes that maximise social value.
FTs are typically appropriate when there is a plausible route to repayment and they can be issued to a variety of beneficiaries including businesses, households, and other countries.
When appraising options for new FTs, there are some key considerations, in addition to those set out in the Green Book for any government intervention, to determine whether an FT is suitable to solve a policy challenge, set out below:
-
Role of government: most FTs will involve (i) government taking on the role of a capital investor where private sector capital markets do not allocate capital in a socially optimal way to viable projects or (ii) improve outcomes by using an FT to deliver a subsidy to address externalities and therefore change the behaviour of economic actors. Government intervention typically has a social cost from raising funds via taxation or borrowing, which needs to be factored into use of FTs.
-
Market failures: government interventions should typically focus on fixing identified market failures. This is where socially optimal outcomes are not realised by markets and can either be a complete market failure (if the market does not function at all) or a partial market failure (if the market functions but in a suboptimal way). Given FTs are an intervention that closely approximates financing available from private capital markets, there should be a clear explanation of why the private sector has not been able to offer these financial products and FTs should be designed to avoid crowding-out private sector capital. Box 2.A outlines a non-exhaustive list of market failures that can be addressed by FTs, together with some relevant examples.
Box 2.A Market failures that can be addressed by FTs
Intervening in the provision of capital
Information asymmetry: market participants can have different levels of information about projects that affect investment decisions and can lead to under-provision of finance. For example, a founding objective of the British Business Bank was to address an asymmetry of information between SMEs and providers of finance.[footnote 8]
Short-termism: investors may under-invest in longer-term projects that may ultimately deliver greater societal benefits and instead focus on shorter-term projects. For example, British Patient Capital was launched to support long-term investment in innovative firms with high growth potential.[footnote 9]
Macroeconomic instability: during an economic downturn, there can be an under-supply of credit as investors may have reduced capital or risk appetite, which means otherwise viable businesses cannot access finance. For example, the Covid-19 Bounce Back Loan Scheme provided 100% guarantees to the lending market for loans to viable firms during the pandemic.[footnote 10]
Risk-tolerance absorption: investors’ degree of insolvency risk means they have a lower risk appetite than government who can invest in projects with larger risks. For example, the National Wealth Fund makes equity investments into infrastructure projects which may carry higher levels of risk than capital markets can absorb.[footnote 11]
Market capacity constraints: investors may have reduced appetite for some investment areas, e.g., potentially due to regulatory impacts or reduced profit margins. Some investors are regulated to manage their investment portfolio, including limiting concentration of risk in certain sectors or markets. The UK Export Finance Direct Lending Facility provides loans to buyers of UK goods, allowing exports to be financed where commercial bank capacity is limited.[footnote 12]
Other Market Failures
Positive externality: some activities cause a positive spillover effect that would not be realised by an investing business, which government can support through an investment at a favourable repayment rate. For example, student loans tackle the externality of education, whereby higher education has benefits for society beyond the individual, through offering loans which would not be commercially available to reduce barriers to participation.
Negative externality: government can subsidise actions to reduce activities by individuals or organisations that cause an indirect cost borne by society, such as pollution. For example, the UKRI Innovation Loans programme has funded various R&D projects to develop new technologies for renewable power generation, supporting the reduction of carbon emissions.[footnote 13]
-
Additionality: this is when government investment leads to activity that would not occur absent intervention. For FTs, this could be unlocking a specific project that would not have been funded, at least in full or as quickly, by the private sector. More broadly, it could also include fostering development of a new or expanding market over time. At a macroeconomic level, to be additional FTs must boost capacity on the supply side of the economy over the medium-term to a greater extent than any nearer-term crowding-out effect from reduced private investment. Evidence of additionality should align with the Green Book’s principles on impact evaluation.
-
Concessionality: to minimise market distortion, concessionality (where government invests on terms more favourable than the market) should be limited to where necessary to achieve policy objectives and compliant with subsidy control legislation. This is important where government is investing in markets where there is an under (but partial) supply of private capital, or directly co-investing with private investors, because issuing concessional FTs in these cases can unintentionally crowd out private finance on a pricing basis.
-
Comparing to grants, guarantees, regulation, or tax: other types of intervention may represent better value for money than FTs. Government should trade off using grants, guarantees, regulation or tax against use of an FT or alternatively FTs may be used alongside these interventions to complement them. Any interactions with wider policy interventions should be considered when assessing the use of an FT, as financing interventions often need to be sequenced with wider policies to address market failures in a specific part of the economy.
What types of FTs exist?
Table 2.1 outlines broad categories of FT, and table 2.2 outlines other instruments that can achieve policy goals in a similar way. The instruments listed in 2.2 are not classified as FTs but may have some similar characteristics and fulfil similar policy objectives.
Table 2.1 Types of financial transaction
Type | Summary |
---|---|
Commercial loans | A loan issued to a business, project, individual or household, which must be repaid at maturity and charges interest at market rates. |
Concessional loans | A loan that charges interest below market rates. This may offer a positive return if income generated is above government’s cost of borrowing, but also could be loss-making. |
Deferred interest loans | A loan that charges interest, but interest payments are deferred for a specified period until the loan matures to ease cashflow challenges for borrowers. |
Direct Equity | When government provides capital through purchasing shares in a business or project in exchange for ownership. |
Fund Investment (Equity) | When government invests equity via a fund structure, alongside private investors. A fund is a product that government owns a share of, combining a pool of investments (e.g., a mix of loans, equity, and debt securities). |
Mezzanine finance (loan and equity) | When government provides a loan that can be converted into an equity stake if a business or project cannot repay the loan in full. |
Table 2.2 Other financial instruments
Type | Summary |
---|---|
Guarantees* | When government agrees to pay all or part of a financial instrument in event of non-payment or loss of value, charging a fee. Guarantees can present a similar type of credit risk as loans. |
Insurance or Indemnities | When government provides coverage for some of the losses of an insured party in certain circumstances. Indemnities cover the risk that an event materialises, rather than a borrower not repaying obligations. |
Convertible grants** | A grant which converts to an equity stake or loan upon reaching pre-agreed conditions. |
*Some types of guarantees are classified as FTs (e.g., standardised guarantees where a large volume of guarantees are issued on identical terms and conditions.)
**Will be FTs when the conditions are met but will be treated as grants before that point. A conditional loan will also fall under this category.
How should government design FTs?
Once a government organisation has decided that an FT may be an appropriate intervention, it should be designed to ensure value for money. Key considerations for policy design are reflected in Annex E, which sets out standardised information that must be provided to the Treasury through the Financial Transaction checklist.
Key considerations
Counterparties and revenue stream: mapping out which counterparties are involved in a transaction will clarify its functioning. This includes who is involved in the supply or value chain that government is investing or lending in, risks to these chains, and how these risks are shared between government and the investee. For example, for a business this will include where their demand comes from and the revenue that will repay the loan or drive equity growth. For an individual or household, it includes factors like creditworthiness or earnings. (Section 1 and 3 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Subsidy control: government FTs will create a lower level of market distortion than grants, but they still need to comply with the Subsidy Control Act 2022, which should be considered at an early stage and resolved prior to concluding negotiations with private sector counterparties.[footnote 14] (Section 1 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Box 2.B Overview of Subsidy Control Rules
The subsidy control regime aims to prevent public authorities from giving financial advantages to businesses in a way that could create excessive distortions of competition. There are seven principles that should guide consideration of whether to implement a subsidy:
A - Subsidies should have a specific policy objective to remedy an identified market failure or address an equity rationale.
B - Subsidies should be proportionate to their specific policy objective and limited to what is necessary to achieve it.
C - Subsidies should bring about a change of behaviour for the beneficiary which would not happen without the subsidy.
D - Subsidies should not normally compensate for costs the beneficiary would have funded in the absence of a subsidy.
E - Subsidies should be a suitable policy instrument for the specific objective, which can’t be achieved by other, less distortive, means.
F - Subsidies should be designed to achieve their policy objective while minimising negative effects on competition and investment.
G - Subsidies’ beneficial effects should outweigh any negative effects, in particular on competition, trade and investment.
Pricing and fiscal Impact: understanding appropriate pricing of an FT will affect delivery. This should be anchored around government’s cost of borrowing, but more importantly should reflect policy goals. If an FT is bankable and seeking to crowd-in co-investment, investing ‘pari passu’ (on equal terms to the private sector) may be suitable to maximise VfM and avoid crowding out. In other cases, an FT may need to be priced below the market, or even below government’s cost of borrowing (a loss-making FT), to transfer risk to government to achieve policy objectives, subject to consideration of subsidy control. Pricing also drives fiscal impacts, which should be calculated over the lifetime of an FT. (Sections 1 and 2 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Exit strategy: for FT interventions, government should either clearly articulate an exit strategy at the outset to maximise returns or outline the policy rationale for holding the asset in perpetuity. For a loan, the exit will be its tenor whereas for an equity investment this will be a planned IPO or trade-sale. Interventions aiming to establish commercial viability for a new technology or sector should consider how support can be tapered over time to transfer risk from government to a new commercial sector. (Section 3 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Risk exposure and management: it is important to understand the level of risk that an FT exposes government to, including the types of risks (see table 3.2 for examples), the scale of losses that could be experienced in a downside scenario, and triggers for this materialising. Public financial institutions and other organisations managing large FT portfolios should have risk exposure limits in place, based on economic capital models. (Section 4 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Managing fraud and error risk: when government provides loans or investments, it may be exposed to risk of fraudulent claims or issuing funds to a party in error. To guard against this, it is important to define robust eligibility criteria in design of FT programmes and ensure adequate capability and processes are in place for upstream due diligence on investments and downstream recovery of erroneous payments. Departments and public financial institutions can engage the Public Sector Fraud Authority on their approach to managing fraud and error, as appropriate. (Section 4 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Classification: consideration should be given as to whether the terms of a proposed investment mean that the public sector will control the investee or bear the majority of its risk and reward, causing a private sector entity to be reclassified to the public sector. The ONS is responsible for determining whether bodies should be classified to the public sector and use international statistical guidance to do so. Departments and public financial institutions should engage their Treasury spending team early in the policy development process if a potential FT may pose classification risks, who will liaise with Treasury classification experts. (Section 4 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Expertise and public financial institutions: FTs involve complex instruments and commercial negotiations, so should be managed by bodies with suitable expertise and experience generating, developing, and implementing FTs. All large-scale, high-risk, or complex FTs and guarantees should be delivered by expert public financial institutions (see annex A for a list of bodies that have been designated under this framework) unless otherwise agreed by the Treasury. They should be involved early in the design of any FT they are intended to deliver on behalf of a department. (Section 5 of Annex E – the FT Checklist).
Box 2.C Other considerations in policy design
For loans
Creditworthiness – when issuing loans, consideration should be given to creditworthiness of the borrowers, to ensure understanding of the risk of default that the loan exposes the government to.
Interest and repayment – the financial return will be dictated by the interest a lender charges the borrower as a share of the principal (i.e., the amount loaned) and the term date for repaying the principal.
Tenor – the term of the loan to maturity should be set out clearly in contract when the loan is agreed. This can be minimised to reduce risk and make sure that capital is returned to government.
Collateral – it could represent value for money to require recipients of loans to post collateral to minimise the risk held by government or alternatively to allow government to take security over an asset, on insolvency of a borrower, to repay a loan.
Seniority – where government secures the status of a senior lender, i.e., that borrowers shall reimburse government before any other creditor, this should reduce the credit risk associated with a loan although it may also limit the efficacy of an intervention.
For equity investments
Equity stake – the size of stake should be limited to avoid inadvertent reclassification to the public sector, alongside consideration of other factors like control taken. Taking a majority stake in a company will lead to classification to the public sector; smaller stakes can still result in reclassification depending on the overall level of control exerted.
Shareholder responsibility – direct equity investments require actively exercising shareholder responsibilities via an expert function such as UKGI or public financial institutions.
Dividend – government should consider what dividend it receives when assessing the value for money of an equity investment, as well as the status of its stock (e.g., preferred stock gives a higher claim to dividends and more shareholder protections).
Support in developing FT proposals
Various bodies can provide support in developing FT proposals:
- Spending teams in the Treasury are an initial port of call in the idea generation stage to provide advice when considering whether an FT is a suitable intervention and on the classification of transactions.
- UKGI can advise departments on various technical issues like understanding risk, pricing an FT, modelling income, and developing delivery models. UKGI can also advise on complex transactions through their lifecycle, including on terms, deal tactics and contingency planning. UKGI can be contacted at UKGIAdvisory@ukgi.org.uk.
- Finally, when departments deliver an FT via a public financial institution, their expertise and the views of their sponsor department should be incorporated early in the design of that FT.
3. Delivery through expert institutions
Overview
The most suitable institutions to deliver FTs and guarantees are public financial institutions set up as centres of expertise in the management of financial instruments, who have appropriate staff, institutional design, and risk management models.
To ensure value for money, all large-scale, complex, or high-risk FTs and guarantees should be delivered by public financial institutions designated under this framework, unless otherwise agreed by Treasury. These institutions are subject to bespoke spending controls.
The current list of designated public financial institutions is set out in Annex A and will be updated on an ongoing basis.
Public financial institutions
Controls for managing public financial institutions
To ensure the right balance between robust controls and commercial flexibility, public financial institutions should be managed as investment bodies, not as if they were spending departments.
This means that typically, the Treasury, in conjunction with the sponsor department, will manage public financial institutions’ financial impact by setting a total capacity, a risk limit, a returns target, and an annual FT limit, instead of setting budgets at Spending Reviews. In some cases, it may still be appropriate to manage public financial institutions in DEL and entities in central government still require parliamentary approval of spending via the estimates process.
The financial controls applied to public financial institutions are:
- A total capacity: how much capital a public financial institution holds to invest in FTs and guarantees before any recycling of returns and therefore its total spending allocation. Changing a public financial institution’s total capacity will affect the size of its balance sheet.
- A risk limit: all FTs carry the inherent risk of potential losses. A risk limit will place a constraint on the level of risk that a public financial institution can undertake by setting a ceiling on the scale of losses it should experience in a low probability downside economic scenario. Once set, institutions are expected to manage their risk exposure within this limit. Risk limits should be set using an economic capital-based approach, as set out in Chapter 4.
- A returns target: public financial institutions should have a financial returns target to embed commercial discipline in their management and define their investment approach. If institutions have a rate of return below government’s cost of borrowing, costs incurred worsen the government’s fiscal metrics and need to be traded off with other spending. Returns targets are covered in Chapter 4 and Annex B.
- An annual FT limit: to place an upper bound on the cash requirement of a public financial institution, which will not typically be a binding constraint as it should be set above the expected annual expenditure of the public financial institution.
These controls do not remove existing governance within public financial institutions – they should be implemented through an approach agreed with the senior management and board, alongside the sponsor department and Treasury. The spending of public financial institutions still affects departmental budgets and should be forecast based on projected investments agreed via their business planning.
The Treasury will publish any changes to the above control levers for designated public financial institutions at fiscal events.
Public financial institution designation process
Organisations are designated as public financial institutions based on the criteria set out in this chapter, at the discretion of the Chief Secretary to the Treasury. This is an administrative designation for spending control purposes and does not relate to the statistical definition of public financial corporations.
Annex A sets out the current list of designated public financial institutions. This list will be added to on an ongoing basis by reform of existing bodies to align with these criteria or creation of new entities. This status can be withdrawn by the Treasury as well as granted.
Departments can put the case to the Treasury for new entities to become public financial institutions at any time. To do so, they should provide a submission that sets out how an institution they sponsor either already meets the criteria or provide a clear time-bound plan for institutional design or reform to achieve the criteria. The Treasury would expect this will normally be done in parallel to a business case for either a new or expanded FT programme or portfolio that the department expects the newly designated public financial institution to deliver.
Public financial institution criteria
The Treasury does not expect all public financial institutions to be designed identically, as different models can achieve similar outcomes. The Treasury does expect that entities seeking to become public financial institutions meet the following criteria or show how the intent of each criterion can be achieved by other means. The criteria are:
- Type of organisation that can be designated: public financial institutions will typically be arm’s length bodies (ALBs), non-ministerial departments or public financial corporations (depending on their exact design). Subsidiaries or other sub-divisions of these entities can be designated as public financial institutions on the condition that they have clearly identifiable and separatable financial statements through which their returns target and risk limits for their FT and guarantee portfolio can be managed and all other criteria are met. This will be appropriate where the wider ALB delivers large grant programmes, which would not be consistent with a public financial institution’s primary activity, but where there are policy benefits to managing the grant and FT programmes within one entity.
- Primary activity: the principal activity of public financial institutions should be making equity investments, loans, guarantees, or other activities intended to generate a financial return. This should be their area of specialist delivery, with institutional design tailored to support this. While some expenditure, for example on administration, will not be investments, most of their expenditure should take the form of financial activity (even if in some cases the entities or assets invested in are classified to the public sector). Non-investment expenditure should be covered by investment income when institutions are mature.
- Operationally independent: public financial institutions should usually be authorised to make day-to-day investment decisions independently, based on strategic objectives and principles set by ministers within specified limits and delegated authorities set by their sponsor department and agreed with the Treasury. Ministers or departments can only request public financial institutions make investments in specific companies or projects that fall outside the institution’s usual investment criteria via a designated and transparent process. This is to ensure that public financial institutions can make investment decisions at arm’s-length from government, with autonomy to identify investment opportunities through market engagement, set their own pricing for transactions, assess whether an investment represents good value, and manage risk of their portfolio.
- Expertise and capability: public financial institutions should employ staff with suitable expertise to manage complex financial instruments and should have sufficient organisational capabilities to manage a significant investment portfolio. This should include senior leadership with relevant experience, an appropriate remuneration framework, strong governance for making independent investment decisions, robust capital management processes, and good systems and controls for risk and financial crime management.
- Balance sheet: public financial institutions should manage their FTs and guarantees as a holistic portfolio, with institutions that also issue some grants having a segregated financial instrument balance sheet for management and audit purposes. Beyond this, the Treasury’s preference is that public financial institutions should be set up either as government-owned companies with their own balance sheet financed through Treasury or department provided equity and debt, or as non-ministerial departments mirroring this arrangement. If specifically agreed by the Treasury and where there is a clear value for money case, institutions can borrow directly from financial markets.
- Investment limits: the investment limits of public financial institutions will be capped. This will typically be operationalised by providing public financial institutions with equity and debt financing, both of which are limited by agreement with the sponsor department and Treasury, grant funding where they have a subsidised rate of return, or another form of cash spending control (such as DEL budgets).
Box 3.A Balance sheet of a public financial institution
As set out in the example below, a public financial institution should preferably be financed by equity and debt finance on their balance sheet (in some cases just equity). The sum of their finance is equal to the total capacity of the organisation to make investments.

For equity finance, targeted returns are agreed between the public financial institution, the sponsor department and Treasury, to be recycled or taken as a dividend. For debt, this must be repaid to the Treasury or sponsor at the gilt rate plus an administration fee.
In this example, the £240 million from debt financing costs would be repaid and the £200 million made on equity returns would be recycled in the institution or returned to the sponsor department.
-
Rate of return or financial objectives: public financial institutions should set a target rate of return of at least the government’s cost of borrowing (see Chapter 4 and Annex B), or an equivalent arrangement, as agreed with the sponsor department and Treasury. Public financial institutions should set a target at the portfolio-level and this return will be targeted over time not year-on-year. The targeted rate of return can be subsidised by departments to allow the institution to make investments that return less income to support policy objectives (see Chapter 4 and Annex C). Where this occurs, the costs will be traded-off with other spending within the constraints of the government’s fiscal rules. In practice, returns target should be adjusted to factor in an institution’s relevant operating expenses and should have a ceiling as well as a floor to ensure that institutions focus on tackling market failures rather than crowding out private capital.
-
Recycling of returns: the public financial institution’s business plan and dividend (or other form of income distribution) policy will set the long-term scale of its balance sheet. As a default, institutions should recycle repayments on principals of loans and sales of equity into new investments, subject to meeting their returns target. This ensures they have a permanent capital base and maintain their existing scale of activity. Profits generated will be reinvested by the institution, enabling them to grow or returned to the sponsor department or Treasury.
Box 3.B Dividend or income distribution policy
In some cases, the sponsor of a public financial institution should set and agree with the Treasury a policy for distributing income generated across the institution’s portfolio when setting its business plan. A dividend or equivalent will be appropriate if it represents better value for money for part of a public financial institution’s returns to be spent on other priorities, rather than being recycled.
If this is desired, the Treasury recommends setting a ceiling for the public financial institution’s rate of return across its portfolio as a method to implement a dividend. This means that if the income exceeds the ceiling in a year, or over a defined period, an agreed portion of income above the ceiling would be taken as a dividend payment or equivalent by the sponsor department or the Treasury.
Sponsor departments are encouraged to consider factors such as the type of capital subject to this policy and legal requirements.
The chart below shows an illustrative returns ceiling of 10% and an average target return of 5%. The public financial institution’s income exceeds the ceiling in year 3 but not on average in the 5-year period.

- Mandated activity or service arm: it may be value for money to use a public financial institution’s expertise to deliver FTs that are intentionally loss-making from the outset to achieve a policy outcome. Loss-making FTs do not make an overall return above government’s cost of borrowing but can be better value for money than grants as they require some repayment. These activities should be transparently reported in the department’s annual report in line with their financial reporting framework. Public financial institutions should manage them via the mandated activity or service arm models, set out in Chapter 4, with any departmental ‘subsidy’ reported in its accounts. As set out above, this may mean the institution has a subsidised rate of return. With agreement of the sponsor department and the Treasury, where a public financial institution generates realised profits above its return target, this may be used to cross-subsidise mandated activity FTs.
- Financial reporting: public financial institutions should produce annual reports and accounts in line with IFRS or the Government Financial Reporting Manual (FReM).
- Risk management: public financial institutions should manage risk through an economic capital-based model described in Chapter 4. This will help government understand its downside risk associated with FTs and guarantees and act as a control on public financial institutions’ risk exposure. Public financial institutions should also have suitable risk management processes in place in line with the Orange Book.[footnote 15]
- Oversight: in the medium-term, the Treasury may consider whether additional oversight is required to manage the economic capital of public financial institutions, for example subjecting them to quasi-regulatory arrangements (as is already the case for some bodies).
Potential flexibilities for public financial institutions
Alongside meeting the criteria, designated public financial institutions may be granted certain flexibilities by the Treasury and its sponsor department to support their abilities to deliver good value investments and function in a commercial and independent way.
These flexibilities are at the discretion of the Chief Secretary to the Treasury and will require a strong business case and demonstration that robust institutional-level controls are in place, such as an economic capital model for managing risk. The flexibilities may include:
- For entities in central government - how annual budgets are set, including management of expenditure in AME. This would mean that the institution’s investments score to CAME FT and expected credit losses, write-offs, and income score to RAME.
- Granting institutions higher delegated limits for Treasury consent than other organisations, with these limits likely varying depending on the type of product (e.g., debt, equity or guarantees).
- A bespoke pay framework for senior and specialist roles, to allow institutions to recruit the external expertise needed to manage complex financial instruments.
- Applying controls on an institution level, not on a programme basis, including the flexibility to deploy cash and risk budgets across their range of programmes, to best meet strategic objectives.
- Providing the certainty of a permanent capital base to support institutions’ market credibility and medium-term business planning.
When public financial institutions should deliver FTs
To ensure value for money and minimise unnecessary risk, all new large-scale, high-risk, or complex FTs and guarantees should be delivered by designated public financial institutions via either their business-as-usual activity, mandated activity, or service arm, unless there is specific Treasury agreement to do otherwise.
- Materiality threshold: ‘large-scale’ is defined as any transaction or programme of transactions that are above a department’s relevant delegated limit. Treasury spending teams should agree FT-specific delegated limits with departments, which can include separate limits for Treasury consent and as a materiality threshold. Any transaction above the relevant limit set should be delivered by a public financial institution unless Treasury agreement is given to do otherwise. When seeking Treasury consent for FTs above their delegated limit, departments are required to return the FT Checklist (Annex E) to provide the information necessary for the Treasury to assess FT bids.
- Complexity and risk level: there may be some FTs or guarantees where, despite being within a department’s delegated limits, they are sufficiently complex or high-risk that they should be delivered by a public financial institution. Table 3.1 covers factors affecting complexity of an FT or guarantee. Departments should make a judgement about how many of these factors are present to support an assessment of whether delivery via a public financial institution is appropriate.
Table 3.1 Factors affecting complexity
Factor | Impact on transaction complexity |
---|---|
Type of Financial Instrument | Instruments like structured finance (e.g., asset backed securities) or equity require more specialist expertise to deliver than simpler products like loans. Non-standard features also increase complexity. |
Transaction Size | Higher value transactions require more robust management processes, including sophisticated due diligence and risk assessment capabilities. |
Duration and Timing | Longer-term transactions are more complex and amplify risk characteristics as they require ongoing management, monitoring and adjustments. Uncertain repayment schedules will further this risk. |
Number of Parties Involved | Transactions involving multiple parties (e.g., buyers, sellers, intermediaries, co-investors, guarantors) tend to be more complex to manage. |
Market Conditions | More volatile or uncertain market conditions require more sophisticated analysis and risk management. |
Table 3.2 also outlines some of the key risks that may be present and need to be managed in delivering a particular FT, guarantee or programme. Departments should similarly make a judgement about how risky a transaction is and the requirements to manage those risks, when considering the appropriate delivery vehicle.
Table 3.2 Common risks present in FTs
Risk type | Description |
---|---|
Credit Risk | The risk that a borrower or counterparty will fail to meet their contractual obligations. This requires thorough credit assessments before entering transactions and ongoing monitoring of the financial health of investees. |
Market Risk | The risk of losses due to changes in demand, interest rates, exchange rates, or asset prices. This requires monitoring of market trends and reducing exposure in isolation and in a portfolio. |
Operational Risk | The risk of losses from process failures, systems, or events (e.g., fraud, cyber risk, system failures). This requires good controls, capability, reporting, and training staff to recognise and address risks. |
Country Risk | The risk of losses due to instability in a country where the transaction is taking place. This requires country-risk assessments before engaging in cross-border transactions. |
Concentration Risk | The risk of losses due to overexposure to a single borrower, sector, or geographic region. This requires diversification of a portfolio and limits on exposure to a single entity or sector. |
Model Risk | The risk of losses due to errors in models used for valuation, risk analysis, or decision-making. This requires capable analytical staff and robust quality assurance processes for critical models. |
Pricing Risk | The risk of pricing an FT without understanding its financial implications, leading to poor VfM. This requires negotiators with commercial expertise and benchmarking to market rates. |
UKGI can be engaged early in policy design to provide expert guidance on whether an FT or guarantee is sufficiently complex or high-risk to necessitate delivery by a public financial institution, and which institution should be considered for the transaction.
Exceptions to delivery via public financial institutions
If departments wish to deliver an FT or guarantee above the materiality threshold or that are judged to be particularly complex or high-risk through a non-designated organisation, they must seek the approval of the Treasury.
Departments must set out why a public financial institution is not the right delivery vehicle, which will usually only be accepted for investments via non-government institutions (e.g., multilateral banks) with equivalent capabilities to public financial institutions.
For FTs above the materiality threshold to be delivered outside of a public financial institution, the Treasury will expect to see the ‘public financial institution criteria’ described in this chapter being applied by the institution responsible for delivery.
4. Transparency on risk and return
Overview
As the government’s investment fiscal rule recognises the value of financial assets like equity and loans generated by FTs and nets these assets off the debt usually required to finance them, it is important to have robust and transparent management of risk and return so that FTs support fiscal sustainability.
To achieve this, FTs must either generate income that covers government’s cost of borrowing or where government makes investments that it expects at the outset to be loss-making, costs must be transparently recognised in budgets in line with an entity’s financial reporting framework. This ensures use of FTs do not worsen debt, as the loss-making element of any FT programme will be reflected in the OBR’s fiscal forecast and traded-off within the government’s fiscal rules.
In addition, government will set a limit on exposure to unexpected losses from FTs in remote economic scenarios, using an economic capital approach to constrain their risk within a defined limit.
A government financial investment report
Government will be transparent about the investments it is making on behalf of taxpayers and ensure all relevant information is accessible to the public and to Parliament.
It will publish an annual Government Financial Investment Report, setting out the financial assets owned by departments and public financial institutions, their latest valuations, their financial performance, and policy benefits achieved. This assessment will examine FTs at a portfolio or institution level. Over time, the report will also assess risk in downside economic stress scenarios, in line with best practice applied in the banking sector.
The report will be delivered by UKGI, the government’s centre of expertise for corporate finance and corporate governance. The government will ensure the information used in this report is robust and independently verified, particularly on the valuation of government’s assets. This report will use asset valuations drawn from government accounts audited by the National Audit Office (NAO) as well as other relevant unaudited information. The Treasury is working with the Comptroller and Auditor General to ensure that the report builds on the existing audits of asset valuations appropriately.
The first iteration of the report will be produced in Autumn 2025 and published annually thereafter.
Targeting a suitable rate of return
All FT programmes and public financial institutions should have a target rate of return to embed good commercial management behaviours. Some investment losses will occur in any portfolio, so for public financial institutions rates of return should be targeted at an institution or portfolio level and for departments at a programme level.
A fiscally neutral baseline
The government’s investment rule recognises where the value of a financial asset offsets the liability usually incurred to finance an FT. When individual FTs or programmes generate a return that covers the government’s cost of borrowing, they are fiscally neutral. This cost of borrowing is the relevant gilt rate (see Annex B) – the cost that the government must pay to service debt issued to fund FTs. In practice, FTs will be priced to also adjust for risk (e.g., credit or investment risk) and cover relevant operating expenses.
The fiscal implications of FT programmes should be judged against this fiscally neutral baseline, but FTs can still be value for money if they generate a lower rate of return but deliver social benefits. The use of this baseline is not a value judgement on the appropriate pricing of FTs, but rather a tool for assessing their fiscal implications. Indeed, all government spending, which is largely funded through taxation or borrowing, has a social cost, and generating a rate of return at or above the government’s cost of borrowing may not be sufficient for an FT intervention to be welfare-generating in an economic sense.
Annex B outlines guidance and the methodology that public financial institutions and departments should use when assessing returns of new investments against the government’s cost of borrowing and setting an appropriate returns target.
Public financial institutions’ returns target
As set out in chapter 3, public financial institutions should be set a returns target of at least the fiscally neutral baseline. This returns target should also recognise relevant operating expenses.
In some cases, it may be suitable for this rate of return to be subsidised by departments where these costs cannot be offset by the returns from other FTs, to allow the institution to make loss-making investments that support policy goals. This departmental ‘subsidy’ will be treated like other spending, enabling ministers to determine the most effective means to deliver policy priorities. When public financial institutions and sponsor departments set a returns target, they should recognise the amount and timing of any ‘subsidy’ received from departments to avoid double counting or timing mismatches.
In other cases, it may be suitable for the institution to target a more commercial return to avoid crowding out private capital on a pricing basis or account for their portfolio risk. This judgement should be taken based on the specific market and policy context in which each institution operates, with the target return and level of any ‘subsidy’ agreed with the sponsor department and Treasury.
The returns target should be used in conjunction with several other performance measures that assess the public financial institution’s wider policy impact, the relative importance of which should be agreed between public financial institutions, their sponsor department, and relevant departments with a delivery interest as appropriate. Full adherence to this framework is required regardless of satisfying any broader performance measures.
Public financial institutions should write annually to their sponsor department and the Treasury to set out their performance against their returns targets and explain any factors driving significant variance from their target, with all parties recognising that the inherently volatile nature of investments will mean that a prudently managed investment portfolio may underperform or overperform in any given year.
A robust approach to managing risk
Overarching risk management principles
When the government undertakes financial investments, it is taking on the risk of unexpected losses. All government institutions managing an FT or guarantee portfolio are expected to have robust arrangements to control risk in line with the Orange Book.[footnote 16]
Appropriate governance arrangements must be in place, setting out clear roles and responsibilities for the Board (or equivalent), Audit and Risk Committees, and Chief Risk Officers with respect to managing risk across the organisation. The three lines of defence as outlined in the Orange Book should be implemented to ensure day-to-day risk management is supported by fit-for-purpose risk policies, frameworks, and training. In addition, overall organisational risk management should be independently assured by a function internal to government.
These processes should cover all financial and operational risks associated with an FT or guarantee portfolio, such as those set out in table 3.2. This should include robust arrangements to manage fraud, in line with standards set by the Public Sector Fraud Authority (PSFA), including financial impact targets for minimising fraud and error to be agreed with the PSFA where appropriate and proportionate.
Setting an economic capital-based risk limit
Many regulated financial organisations hold capital to protect them from insolvency and use economic capital models to help them understand their downside risk, which informs decisions on the amount of capital held. To help government understand its downside risk from FTs, public financial institutions must implement an economic capital-based model. A limit will then be set to control the amount of risk that a public financial institution is subject to, which should be agreed with the sponsor department and the Treasury.
The economic capital limit will either be based on the equity financing of an institution or will be virtual economic capital (VEC), where an organisation does not hold equity and instead the economic capital limit represents a maximum value-at-risk for its portfolio up to a certain confidence level in a low-probability downside scenario.
It is expected that these limits, in most cases, should allow for a higher risk appetite than regulated financial organisations to support policy objectives and deliver investments that are additional to financing available from private capital markets. The risk limit set should also be tailored to the specific mandate of each institution.
Guarantees will be controlled in the same way as FTs for the purpose of economic capital limits, as they involve similar risk-taking and so managing them under a single framework aids consistency and trading-off risk exposures from different interventions.
Box 4.A Economic capital models
Economic capital reflects the expected riskiness of investments and measures the amount of capital reserve needed to absorb downside loss events. An economic capital limit will place a constraint on the level of risk that an entity can undertake. It does this by setting a ceiling on the scale of downside losses that an entity or programme should experience in a low probability outcome.

Traditionally, an economic capital model is linked to capital, i.e., that financial institutions can only take on risk such that potential downside losses can be met from their equity in all but the most remote scenario. This is the approach taken by private sector banks under Prudential Regulation Authority (PRA) regulations.
Once public financial institutions have been set an economic capital or VEC limit, they are expected to manage their risk exposure within this limit, maintaining an appropriate level of headroom against the limit and trading off capital allocation between different FTs and guarantees to maximise impact against their policy mandate.
Implementing economic capital-based modelling
To implement this, public financial institutions should model total potential losses their portfolio could face in a low probability (e.g., a 1 in 100) outcome. Key components of modelling include all material risks faced by an institution, such as credit risk, market risk, operational risk, country risk, and concentration risk (see table 3.2 for definitions). Institutions should also consider diversification of their financial assets, as well as correlations in potential risk triggers across assets held.
Public financial institutions should then for all transactions they undertake, assess the impact on economic capital or VEC consumption. They should also determine their current exposure by retrospectively calculating the capital or VEC consumed by their existing portfolio of FTs and guarantees (except for those delivered via the service arm).
Alongside an economic capital model, public financial institutions should undertake regular stress-tests for their FT and guarantee portfolio, in line with best practice in the banking sector.
Annex D sets out an example of a standardised economic capital model, which is one approach that can be used depending on the nature of investments held by and risks facing the institution. Where standard approaches are judged to be unsuitable or when modelling could be improved, institutions should develop their own modelling approaches calibrated to specific risks they face. These methodologies should be quality-assured by a Treasury-approved organisation.
In some cases, the implementation of an economic capital model will be done over time as organisations develop their level of sophistication. However, the ability to model and manage risk effectively within an exposure limit, or an agreed time bound plan to develop this capability, is a pre-requisite to consideration of any changes to the capitalisation of public financial institutions.
When it is proportionate to the scale of financial risk taken by FTs or guarantees managed by departments, the Treasury will work with departments to implement a VEC model in line with this guidance. In addition, the Treasury will explore if VEC should be applied to government-provided insurance.
Understanding government’s overall risk exposure
The Treasury will use aggregate information on the risks across government’s FT and guarantees portfolio to consider an appropriate overall level of financial risk for government to hold and support decisions on trading off exposure across parts of government’s portfolio.
To facilitate this, the Treasury will work with public financial institutions and departments over a defined period to agree a set of consistent parameters, scenarios, and stress tests to be used in downside risk modelling, so that these may become aligned over time.
In time, the annual Government Financial Investment Report will report on the aggregate level of risk taken across government’s investment portfolio and assess economic stress scenarios.
Budgeting for losses
Treating loss-making FTs like other spending
It is possible that the best value for money way to achieve a policy objective may be a loss-making FT. This is an FT priced to generate a rate of return below the gilt rate, so the income to government is expected from the outset to be lower than government’s cost of borrowing. In practice, individual FTs should also be priced to adjust for risk and cover relevant operating expenses.
This framework ensures that the cost of loss-making FTs is recognised by departments and that the loss-making element is treated as spending and is traded off with other resource costs, in line with the department’s financial reporting framework.
When making decisions on budget allocations, the Treasury will primarily consider the fiscal rather than the budgetary impact of a proposal. Annex E sets out the FT checklist for new FT proposals, which includes requirements on modelling financial impacts.
How losses affect departmental budgets
The government accounts for the risk and crystallisation of losses through its IFRS-based accounting regime and associated budgeting system, which transparently reflects their cost within departmental budgets. This framework is set out in detail in CBG. For example:
- Expected credit losses generally score to resource DEL. The estimate reflects a probability-weighted amount determined by evaluating a range of possible outcomes.
- Other changes in the fair value of financial assets generally score to resource AME.
- If government issues FTs below their fair value, the associated loss – i.e., difference between the transaction price and fair value – generally scores to resource DEL.
- Write-offs score in resource DEL and worsen net financial debt and public sector net investment, but do not affect the current budget balance.
Where the Chief Secretary to the Treasury has agreed that the spending of a specific public financial institution will be managed in AME, all the charges above will score in Resource AME not DEL.
Mandated activity and service arm models
Loss-making FTs via public financial institutions
Where there is a strong rationale for intervention, public financial institutions and departments can collaborate to develop blended finance solutions. This can include loss-making FTs as well as combinations of grant or other forms of spending together with FTs.
FTs should be delivered via public financial institutions wherever possible – including loss-making FTs – as their expertise ensures schemes are well-designed and maximise impact for their costs. Departments seeking to deliver a loss-making FT should engage early with a public financial institution and its sponsor department to support design and delivery. This should be via a project approach, with both parties committing expertise and resources, and co-designing interventions. Any decision to proceed should consider the institution’s capacity and trade-offs with their core delivery responsibilities.
This framework provides two models for delivering loss-making FTs through designated public financial institutions:
- A mandated activity model, where public financial institutions hold all the risk and return, with a fixed ‘subsidy’ provided by a department to cover the loss-making element; and
- A service arm model, where departments hold risk and return, and the FT sits on the department’s balance sheet, managed in DEL.
The Treasury’s preference is that loss-making FTs are delivered via the mandated activity model by default because it transparently records income foregone compared to an institution’s returns target and best leverages the institution’s expertise to manage risk.
The mandated activity model
The mandated activity model is available to all departments exploring FTs in areas covered by a public financial institution’s remit. A public financial institution has Accounting Officer (AO) responsibility for value for money decisions under this model, so it is important for them to be involved from the outset. Some key aspects of the model are:
- For loans that charge interest rates less than government’s cost of borrowing and additional pricing for risk, the departmental ‘subsidy’ amount will be the spread between the interest rate the public financial institution would have otherwise charged (factoring in risk and their returns target) and the rate the department desires to charge. The ‘subsidy’ will be paid each year to subsidise interest income foregone and will be agreed and fixed for the department at the outset. It is important that public financial institutions retain control of pricing of FTs to maintain independence and commercial rigour in management of FTs, although this does not necessarily mean a commercial price, particularly where there is policy rationale to provide concessionality.
- A departmental ‘subsidy’ can be provided at a transaction, programme, or whole institution level. A departmental ‘subsidy’ to a whole public financial institution would be appropriate if a department expected, based on the market it is investing in, that it should be structurally loss-making to achieve its policy goals.
- Budgetary impacts depend on the relationship between the institution and the subsidising department. An institution subsidised by its sponsor department will not have a direct budgetary impact, as it is a transaction within the departmental group. If a department is subsiding an institution sponsored by another department, then this will have a budgetary impact. Further details are set out in Annex C.
- The level of ‘subsidy’ will not necessarily mirror the cash requirements of mandated activity nor a public financial institution’s drawdowns from its sponsor department or the Treasury.
- With agreement of the sponsor department and Treasury, where a public financial institution generates realised (i.e., not forecast) profits above its return target, this may be used to cross-subsidise mandated investments. The institution must still achieve its return target and ensure costs of mandated FTs are transparently recorded.
The service arm model
Service arm FTs sit on the department’s balance sheet and the public financial institution acts as an agent for the department, administering investments and providing support to the department in negotiating and structuring any deal. Departments provide all funding, hold all the risk, budget for the FT in DEL, and have AO responsibility for value for money decisions. For this support, public financial institutions typically charge a fee to cover their operating expenses.
The service arm will be suitable for one-off transactions, crisis interventions, or programmes where changing the mandate of an existing institution or setting up a new one is not proportionate.
Departments should discuss with their Treasury spending team if they wish to use a public financial institution’s service arm.
5. Treasury approval for financial transactions
The business case process for FTs
When a department has a clear rationale for intervention via an FT or programme of FTs, and the key material characteristics of the investment are identified, then the intervention should be assessed using existing frameworks for considering the use of public resources.
Application of the Five Case Model
The Green Book is guidance issued by the Treasury on how to appraise policies, programmes, and projects, within which the Five Case Model is the key approach to help government evaluate spending proposals. There are some key FT-specific considerations for each part of a business case, building on the principles set out in Chapter 2.
- Strategic Case: this initial stage requires an explanation of the objective that the FT seeks to meet and its links to Ministerial or wider government objectives. Here, it would be important to articulate the market failure that the FT seeks to address, including why private capital markets have been unable to provide this financial product and how this intervention will be additional to private finance.
- Economic Case: this stage would be where most of the option appraisal takes place. The FT should be appraised against other interventions such as grant spending, guarantees, and regulation, but also the ‘business as usual’ or ‘do nothing’ option. Each option should be appraised as to what extent they achieve the policy objective and to what degree they provide value for money. This may be the point when an option should be removed from the longlist.
- Commercial Case: this is the point at which consideration of counterparties involved should be articulated, with an emphasis on understanding the risks (e.g., credit risk or operational risk) involved in delivery, where the balance of risk lies between the counterparties and government, as well as how negotiable any arrangement is. This might be demonstrated via the business plan of the counterparty or a summary of the key elements of the transaction(s). Such analysis will bring out how credible an investment deal will ultimately be.
- Financial Case: here, the pricing and estimated fiscal impact of the FT should be described, alongside budgeting and accounting impacts. The rationale should be presented for why these impacts are affordable for government. This will be supported by forecasting the revenue stream that pays for the income used to repay the FT.
- Management Case: finally, how the intervention will be delivered should be outlined. This includes which public financial institution is delivering the FT or why another organisation is equipped to do so, how ongoing risks will be monitored, and how government will manage any shareholding. In addition, this section should set out how the intervention will be evaluated to apply future learnings at key stage milestones and review points.
The Financial Transaction Checklist
As FTs differ from conventional public spending in several ways, it is important that all relevant FT-specific issues are considered by departments through the business case process. To facilitate this, and to provide standardised information to Treasury ministers on FTs, the Treasury has produced the financial transaction checklist to support departments to consider and communicate this key information.
The financial transaction checklist is required to be completed when Treasury consent is sought for a new FT, either because the FT is novel, contentious, or repercussive, or where FTs are above a department’s delegated limit. It must also be provided alongside business cases for FT budget allocations at fiscal events or Spending Reviews, when requested by the relevant Treasury spending team, or when changing the capitalisation of a public financial institution.
Early engagement on upcoming proposals is encouraged, so it is good practice for a draft or partially completed checklist to be shared with the Treasury to facilitate discussion. The checklist is intended to be a flexible document, so in some cases the questions will be less relevant to a specific FT under consideration. The checklist should be provided to the Treasury alongside a full business case for FT proposals and the checklist should usually be completed and shared with the Treasury first, as the business case will tend to provide more detail.
The checklist should be submitted to the relevant Treasury spending team (responsible for the department’s policy priorities and affordability of any FT), who will work with the Treasury’s Balance Sheet Team (responsible for government’s overall stock of financial assets and FT policy) and the General Expenditure Policy team (responsible for overall control of public spending) to consider the proposal.
The checklist is provided in Annex E with guidance on completing the checklist in Annex F.
Annex A: List of designated public financial institutions
Organisations are designated as public financial institutions based on the criteria set out in Chapter 3, at the discretion of the Chief Secretary to the Treasury.
This list will be updated on an ongoing basis when the Chief Secretary to the Treasury makes decisions to designate any additional bodies as public financial institutions or change the designation of existing bodies.
Current list of designated institutions
The current list of designated public financial institutions that have been deemed to meet the criteria set out include:
- British Business Bank PLC
- British International Investment PLC
- National Wealth Fund Ltd
- UK Export Finance (legally the Export Credits Guarantee Department)
- The Student Loans Company, which does not function like a typical banking institution, has been designated as a public financial institution as they have the requisite capability to manage this unique asset. Student loans are subject to a bespoke set of financial controls and accounting treatment in the National Accounts. The arrangements in place for student loans achieve the same outcome as the controls that are applied to other public financial institutions.
Future designation decisions
The Treasury and Ministry of Housing, Communities and Local Government are working together to ensure a suitable model is in place within Homes England to support delivery of the government’s housing commitments, in line with the principles of this framework.
The Treasury and Department for Energy Security and Net Zero are working together to ensure a suitable model is in place for the delivery of financial instruments by Great British Energy, in line with the principles of this framework, and will consider its designation as a public financial institution in the future.
Annex B: Benchmarking returns to costs of financing FTs
Calculating the cost of financing FTs
Using the relevant gilt rate
As set out in Chapter 4, the government’s cost of financing its FTs should be used as a fiscally neutral baseline by departments and public financial institutions in assessing the fiscal impacts of FT interventions.
In practice, government’s cost of financing its FTs is complex to capture as a single figure. FTs are issued at different times and feed into government’s overall financing requirement. The Debt Management Office (DMO) issues gilts on behalf of HM Treasury, issuing a mix of conventional gilts, index-linked gilts, and Treasury bills across different maturities. Gilt yields also vary, for example being affected by economic conditions and monetary policy. The government also raises finance through National Savings & Investments, taxation, and asset sales.
For costing FTs, organisations should follow best practice approaches and use the market-implied nominal gilt yield for new government borrowing at the point the FTs are issued. The appropriate yield depends on the date the FT is written and its expected duration, and organisations should use gilt yields for a matching period to the expected duration of FTs. The Bank of England and other sources regularly publish gilt yield curves.[footnote 17]
Pricing for risk and relevant operating expenses
To cover its costs, in practice, an FT should be priced to adjust for risk and relevant operating expenses, on top of the government’s cost of borrowing. Pricing for risk entails first identifying and quantifying risks associated with an investment (see Table 3.2) and then calculating the additional return required to reflect the risk taken. Organisations that do not have the expertise to appropriately price for risk should use expert public financial institutions to support delivery of FT programmes or – where it has been agreed with the Treasury that delivery via a public financial institution is inappropriate – departments should draw on technical advice from UKGI on pricing the FT.
Alongside risk, there should be pricing for relevant operating expenses to reflect the costs incurred in managing the FT.
Public financial institution rate of return
Setting a returns target
Public financial institutions’ returns targets should be set to at least cover the government’s cost of financing and be agreed via annual business plans or medium-term strategic plans with sponsor departments, the Treasury, and relevant policy departments with a delivery interest as appropriate. This target should be unique to each public financial institution. Sponsor departments can set a returns target for a fixed period to promote stable planning or adjust more regularly depending on the nature of a portfolio. The Treasury reserves the right to reassess returns targets if gilt rates change significantly.
For public financial institutions with an established portfolio, a returns target for an upcoming period should measure the performance of historical and forecast investments over the period a target covers, as illustrated in chart B.1. This is because there is often a time lag between an investment being made and expected returns.
Chart B.1 Indicative example for setting a returns target

Each FT made in a given year will have an associated cost of borrowing incurred, which should be reflected when formulating the target. Organisations should calculate the average duration of investments in their portfolio and use a matching period on a nominal gilt yield curve to establish historical and expected annual gilt yields.
When setting a returns target, sponsor departments and public financial institutions should contact the Treasury for further guidance on applying the relevant gilt rate.
Box B.1 Example of the cost of financing a portfolio
A public financial institution has an existing portfolio of £10bn investments made over 20/21 – 24/25 and expects to make £2bn p.a. investments in 25/26 to 27/28. The institution and sponsor wish to set a fiscally neutral returns target over this three-year period (to 27/28).
They first calculate the ‘average duration’ of investments across the full portfolio by multiplying the value of investments by estimated duration and dividing by the sum of the value of the investments.
This average duration is ten years, so a fiscally neutral returns target uses borrowing costs for a matching period – i.e., the historical ten-year gilt rates and market implied ten-year gilt rate forecast.
The ongoing government debt interest cost incurred in financing the institution’s portfolio (both for historical and forecast investments) as of the final year of the three-year period (27/28) is used to estimate the weighted average cost of financing the portfolio over the period.
This is the sum of: average 10-year gilt rate in the year investments are made * the share of investments made in that year within the portfolio as of 27/28, which is estimated as 3.8%. In practice, a small adjustment may be made for risk and relevant operating expenses.
Year FT is issued (forecast from 25/26) | Average 10-year gilt rate in year FT is issued (%) | Value of FTs made in each year | Share of FTs by year in portfolio as of 27/28 (%) |
---|---|---|---|
20/21 | 0.37 | £1bn | 6.0% |
21/22 | 1.02 | £1bn | 6.0% |
22/23 | 3.04 | £3bn | 19.0% |
23/24 | 4.09 | £2bn | 12.5% |
24/25 | 4.29 | £3bn | 19.0% |
25/26 | 4.68 | £2bn | 12.5% |
26/27 | 4.76 | £2bn | 12.5% |
27/28 | 4.83 | £2bn | 12.5% |
Total | £16bn | 100% |
Subsidising FTs over a period
In some cases, it may be suitable for public financial institutions to have a subsidised rate of return. Departments should use the market implied gilt rate forecast as the benchmark against which to calculate the expected ‘subsidy’ for new investments in a period (see Annex C)
Annex C: The mandated activity and service arm models
Summary
This annex provides further detail on the mandated activity and service arm models. Departments should consult their Treasury spending team for advice on budgeting when considering their use.
The mandated activity model
Under the mandated activity model, public financial institutions deliver structurally loss-making FTs using their own capital and risk appetite, with a ‘subsidy’ from the relevant department to cover the loss-making element. The public financial institution will hold all the risk of the investment and its performance will contribute to the returns target that the institution has been set. As a result, public financial institutions must agree to deliver the FT, as the institution has AO responsibility for the final value for money decision and the department will not face any ongoing risk once the payment has been fixed upfront, with the department having AO responsibility for this ‘subsidy’.
Public financial institutions should have a returns target of at least at the government’s cost of borrowing (see Annex B), alongside accounting for other factors like portfolio risk. When they are asked to make loss-making investments, they forego income from the private sector that would have covered the cost of financing the FT and any risk. This worsens the current budget balance over time. The intent of the departmental ‘subsidy’ is to allow the institution to meet their returns target when making structurally loss-making FTs through a mix of income from the FT and income from the department. This ensures transparency over the fiscal impacts of the activity and protects the institution’s market credibility as a commercial partner to co-investors.
Scale of departmental ‘subsidy’ for loss-making loans and guarantees – the scale of the departmental ‘subsidy’ will be the spread between the price the institution would have otherwise charged to the project and the price the department wishes them to charge. Public financial institutions set this price as they are accountable for their portfolio’s performance. This price may not need to be a commercial price, as public financial institutions may not have a commercial returns target. Departments may provide any level of ‘subsidy’ against this price, subject to normal Treasury consent and subsidy control rules.
The scale of the departmental ‘subsidy’ is the same whether provided by the sponsor department or another department. The department pays this ‘subsidy’ each financial year regardless of performance of the loan. If the loan doesn’t perform, the public financial institution may have to recognise additional expected credit losses or reduced income in their budgets, but as the institution holds the risk this will have no impact on the departmental ‘subsidy’ payment.
With agreement between the public financial institution, the sponsor department and the Treasury, the departmental ‘subsidy’ can be provided directly to the borrower and the institution can charge the borrower the interest they would otherwise charge.
Box C.1 Example of a loss-making loan
A department wishes a public financial institution to issue a 5 year, £100m loan with a 2% interest rate.
Considering credit risk and their returns target, the public financial institution would without the departmental ‘subsidy’ price the loan at 8%. The department wants for the loan to charge a 2% interest rate instead of 8%, to support the policy goals of the department.
The departmental ‘subsidy’ is the spread between the rate the institution would have otherwise charged and the rate that the department wishes them to charge. In this example that is 6% (£6m).
The department pays this ‘subsidy’ each year to the public financial institution regardless of the performance of the loan.
£m | Y0 | Y1 | Y2 | Y3 | Y4 | Y5 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Loan issued & repaid | -100 | 100 | ||||
Income from borrower | 2 | 2 | 2 | 2 | 2 | |
‘Subsidy’ paid to institution | 6 | 6 | 6 | 6 | 6 |
Budgetary impacts depend on whether the institution being subsidised is inside or outside the department’s accounting boundary. If it is inside, then the departmental ‘subsidy’ won’t have a budgetary impact as it is a transfer within the departmental group. If it is outside, the ‘subsidy’ will impact the department’s budget. Scoring will depend on exact policy design, but subsidies compensating public financial institutions for lost interest income are generally RDEL. When a department intends to deliver FTs that require a ‘subsidy’, this will need to be traded off against other forms of spending.
While a ‘subsidy’ within a department’s accounting boundary will not directly impact budgets, it will impact the income and expenditure of the public financial institution. The level of departmental ‘subsidy’ will thus be subject to Treasury spending control as a lever for controlling public financial institutions’ expected income. Changes to the level of departmental ‘subsidy’ have a fiscal impact, so require Treasury consent and may entail offsetting RDEL savings elsewhere. The level of ‘subsidy’ may not always mirror the cash requirements of mandated activity. Public financial institutions should agree an appropriate approach to account for the impact on their returns target with their sponsor department and the Treasury.
Scale of departmental ‘subsidy’ for paying premium for equity. This is where a public financial institution pays more for equity than the value on its balance sheet (as valued by the institution itself, with UKGI providing advice as appropriate), which worsens net financial debt by this difference. Paying a premium for equity is not the same as investing in high-risk equity – it is in effect a mix of a grant and equity investment. The departmental ‘subsidy’ given to the public financial institution reflects this and scores as CDEL grant, whether the institution is inside or outside the department group boundary. A subsidy is not required if differences in valuation are driven by timing and the investment is still consistent with the institution’s returns target. The same outcome is achieved if the institution pays the market price for equity and the department transfers a grant to the investee.
Box C.2 Example of paying a premium for equity
A department wishes a public financial institution to pay £100m for equity that would have a £60m valuation on the institution’s balance sheet if bought. This is in effect a £60m equity transaction and a £40m grant, the latter usually scored to CDEL budgets. The department pays the £40m grant on behalf of the public financial institution, which will not typically have large CDEL budgets. This is paid in the year of the transaction, mirroring the fiscal impact.
Departmental ‘subsidy’ at a programme or institutional level – the examples above are subsidies for individual transactions. In practice, most subsidies will be agreed for FT programmes or the whole institution. The same principles apply – public financial institutions will remain accountable for meeting their returns target, setting out the level of departmental ‘subsidy’ required to deliver a structurally loss-making programme, and hold all risk and return. The ‘subsidy’ is fixed for the department through the period the returns target is set and the institution takes account of ‘subsidy’ income in meeting its returns target. This in effect sets a lower returns target for the institution. When a department provides a ‘subsidy’ to support overall returns of a public financial institution, the institution can deploy that flexibly between its transactions and programmes to best meet its strategic objectives.
Box C.3 Example of subsidising a portfolio of FTs
A public financial institution is forecast to make £2bn p.a. investments over the next three years. The institution and sponsor department judge that to achieve policy goals, these investments should target a 3% return, which is less than their expected cost of financing.
The annual subsidy is the difference between a fiscally neutral return and the 3% expected return. The ‘subsidy’ is fixed upfront, lasts for the duration of investments and is cumulative as FTs are issued.
The average duration of investments is estimated at ten years, so the fiscally neutral return will be government’s borrowing costs over a matching period – i.e., the market-implied ten-year gilt rate forecast.
Forecast Year | New FTs p.a. | Stock of new assets | Average 10-year gilt forecast | ‘Subsidy’ on new FTs issued | Cumulative ‘subsidy’ for the FY |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
25/26 | £2bn | £2bn | 4.68% | £33.6m | £33.6m |
26/27 | £2bn | £4bn | 4.76% | £35.2m | £68.8m |
27/28 | £2bn | £6bn | 4.83% | £36.6m | £105.4m |
Timing and process – agreeing departmental ‘subsidies’ for individual FTs can be done at any time, but for large new programmes or annual or multi-year ‘subsidies’ of public financial institution’s overall rate of return, this should be done at a Spending Review or fiscal event, with the associated fiscal impact scored in the OBR’s forecast.
The service arm model
Under the service arm model, the risk and return of the FT sits with the department, not the public financial institution. This will likely be used where the public financial institution is the agent for delivering the FT. Public financial institutions provide support in pricing, structuring, and delivering the transaction. For this support, public financial institutions will charge a fee to cover their operating expenses.
Service arm FTs have the same budgeting impact as FTs delivered directly by a department – departments will need CDEL FT budget cover and any relevant RDEL or RAME budget cover for charges such as expected credit losses or policy losses.
Annex D: Example of a standard economic capital model
Standard industry approaches
Public financial institutions and departments managing FT or guarantee portfolios at scale will be set an economic capital or virtual economic capital (VEC) limit to manage their risk exposure.
Public financial institutions are encouraged to utilise industry best practice to model, understand and communicate risk. Established methodologies in the banking sector for economic capital modelling stem from Basel III standards put in place to mitigate risks of bank failures. This includes two methodologies for calculating risk-weighted assets – a standardised and internal ratings-based approach.[footnote 18]
The standardised approach is set out in this annex and is one potential model for assigning a risk weighting to individual transactions that corresponds to a level of economic capital consumption. It models credit risk but can be adapted to incorporate other types of risks.
As the model assigns a simple measure of capital requirement to transactions that is not sensitive to specific risks faced by a portfolio, it will likely be preferable for some public financial institutions to do bespoke risk analysis. In some cases, the application of this model may be suitable in absence of well-developed internal models and it is a starting point from which institutions can develop their own modelling. It is for public financial institutions to specify and justify their approach.
Implementing the model
Summary of model and data inputs
The standardised economic capital model first uses standard credit ratings to describe the ability and willingness of a borrower to meet credit obligations in full and on time. Lending considered investment grade is regarded by market participants as lower risk, whereas sub-investment grade lending refers to where a borrower can repay but faces significant uncertainties affecting credit risk.
Table D.1 Credit rating descriptions
Rating | Description |
---|---|
Investment grade | |
AAA to AA- | Borrower has a very strong capacity to meet financial commitments |
A+ to A- | Borrower has a strong capacity to meet financial commitments, but somewhat susceptible to changing economic conditions and circumstances. |
BBB+ to BBB- | Borrower has an adequate capacity to meet financial commitments |
Sub-investment grade | |
BB+ to BB- | Borrower faces major ongoing uncertainties to adverse business and economic conditions. |
B- to B+ | Borrower is more vulnerable to adverse business and economic conditions, but currently has capacity to meet financial conditions. |
Below B- | Borrower is currently vulnerable and dependent on favourable business and economic conditions to meet financial commitments. |
The standardised economic capital model then applies risk weights to the above credit ratings, with differentiation between various types of transactions and beneficiaries, as well as specific approaches to mortgage lending based on loan-to-value (LTV) ratios. Riskier investments carry a higher standardised risk weighting percentage and assumed economic capital consumption.
To calculate the capital requirements for a transaction, the size of the investment is multiplied by the risk weighting: investment amount x % risk weighting = economic capital consumption. The below table outlines the risk weighting for different investment types and for illustrative purposes, capital required for a £100 million investment.[footnote 19]
Table D.2 Risk weightings and economic capital consumption
Rating | Risk Weights* | Capital Required |
---|---|---|
Corporate Lending (CRE 20.43) | ||
AAA to AA- | 1.6% | £1,600,000 |
A+ to A- | 4% | £4,000,000 |
BBB+ to BBB- | 6% | £6,000,000 |
BB+ to BB- | 8% | £8,000,000 |
B- to B+ | 12% | £12,000,000 |
Below B- | 12% | £12,000,000 |
Unrated | 8% | £8,000,000 |
Specialised Lending (CRE 20.51) | ||
AAA to AA- | 1.6% | £1,600,000 |
A+ to below B- | 8% | £8,000,000 |
Construction | 10.4% | £10,400,000 |
Equity Type (CRE 20.57) | ||
Equity (Listed, Liquid) | 20% | £20,000,000 |
Equity (Unlisted, Illiquid) | 32% | £32,000,000 |
Sovereign Debt (CRE 20.7) | ||
AAA to AA- | 0% | £0 |
A+ to A- | 1.6% | £1,600,000 |
BBB+ to BBB- | 4% | £4,000,000 |
BB+ to B- | 8% | £8,000,000 |
Below B- | 12% | £12,000,000 |
Unrated | 8% | £8,000,000 |
Project Finance (CRE 20.51) | ||
Pre-operational phase | 10.4% | £10,400,000 |
Operational phase | 8% | £8,000,000 |
Residential Mortgage Loans (CRE 20.84) | ||
LTV ≤ 60% | 2.8% | £2,800,000 |
60% < LTV ≤ 80% | 3.6% | £3,600,000 |
80% < LTV ≤ 90% | 4.8% | £4,800,000 |
90% < LTV ≤ 100% | 6% | £6,000,000 |
LTV > 100%: 105% | 8.4% | £8,400,000 |
Commercial Mortgage Loans (CRE 20.87) | ||
LTV ≤ 60% | 5.6% | £5,600,000 |
LTV < 60% ≤ 80% | 7.2% | £7,200,000 |
LTV > 80% | 8.8% | £8,800,000 |
Fund Investments (CRE 60) | ||
Look through approach | Weighted average of underlying assets | |
Mandate-based approach | As per the underlying assets and terms | |
Fall-back approach | 100% | £100,000,000 |
*Risk weights include 8% capital adequacy ratio in their calculation for illustrative purposes.
Factoring in other types of risk
The risk weightings above relate to credit risk only. For most public financial institutions, this is the biggest risk to manage, however, it is also possible to model other risks in a downside scenario:
- Concentration risk: the standardised approach may be complemented by a concentration risk add-on to capture single-exposure, sector, or country over-concentrations. The Bank of England provides a framework for computing concentration risk add-ons in their description of PRA’s methodology for setting Pillar 2 Capital.[footnote 20] Other approaches such as stress testing can also be used for this purpose.
- Market risk: the Interest Rate Risk in the Banking Book (IRRBB)[footnote 21] and Internal Capital Adequacy Assessment Process (ICAAP)[footnote 22] frameworks for regulated banks governed by the Bank of England provide guidance on the suitable approach for assessing market risk.
Limitations of the model
In practice, some FTs and guarantees will be riskier, more novel or specialised than investments made by commercial banks. Therefore, the standardised model should be viewed as one of several potential approaches. However, it helps illustrate the concept of applying risk weightings and calculating capital requirements.
The Internal Rating Based (IRB) model is another approach that institutions can implement if it appropriately models the risks faced by an institution. Over time, public financial institutions will likely develop sufficient data and expertise to implement bespoke economic capital-based methodologies for modelling downside risk.
Implementing an economic capital model
Public financial institutions should agree a time-bound plan for implementing an economic capital-based approach with their sponsor department and the Treasury. In some cases, this may need to be a phased approach, while an institution develops its capability, and it will need to be tailored to the risks and data available to an institution.
Annex E: Financial transaction checklist
Overview
The financial transaction checklist provides specific information necessary for Treasury to assess FT bids alongside full business cases.
The checklist is required to be completed when the FT is novel, contentious, or repercussive, or where FTs are above a department’s delegated limit. It must be provided alongside business cases for FT budget allocations at fiscal events or Spending Reviews, when requested by the relevant Treasury spending team, or when changing the capitalisation of a public financial institution.
The checklist seeks to develop common understanding between departments and the Treasury on FT proposals, and the information provided will form the basis of advice to Treasury ministers. The content will not always be the exact final terms of an FT but should be a meaningful approximation. Annex F provides guidance on completion.
If seeking Treasury consent for a guarantee or guarantee scheme, please refer to the Contingent Liability Approval Framework.[footnote 23]
Checklist
1. Strategic case summary
This section asks departments to set out what the FT is, the policy rationale and the value for money case, showing why this FT has been put forward amongst other options.
1.1 What policy change is the FT intended to bring about?
1.2 What is the scale and scope of the intervention? (Number of transactions, lifetime expenditure, indicative size per investment)
1.3 What is the expected start and end date of the FT?
1.4 Who is the economic beneficiary of the FT?
1.5 What are the specific policy objectives of this intervention and how does it support ministerial priorities?
1.6: Please set out a clear articulation of the market failure requiring intervention. Why has the private sector not provided this product?
1.7 Why is an FT the best policy lever to address this market failure compared to alternative interventions or a do-nothing option?
1.8 Will the FT be commercial, concessional but cover the government’s cost of borrowing, or be loss-making and why is this pricing suitable?
1.9 Does this comply with the Subsidy Control Act?
Financial costs
2.1 Fiscal impacts
Please complete the following table summarising fiscal impacts. It is set out such that income is negative and spending is positive. Please articulate your central expectation for returns and valuations such that they are equally likely to be an overestimate or an underestimate.
Financial transaction costing table | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Year | FY-0 | FY-1 | FY-2 | FY-3 | FY-4 | Extend as needed |
(a) Receipts | ||||||
(b) Expenditure | ||||||
of which: | ||||||
(c) Current (operating costs & guarantee fee income, excluding debt interest costs) | ||||||
(d) Capital (loan write-offs and guarantee calls) | ||||||
(e) Debt interest costs | ||||||
(f) Effect on CBB (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) | ||||||
(g) Effect on PSNB (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) | ||||||
(h) Debt securities issued to finance lending | ||||||
(-h) Loan assets | ||||||
(i) Debt securities issued to finance equity investments | ||||||
(-i) Equity assets | ||||||
(j) Revaluation of equity assets (rise in value = negative) | ||||||
(k) Effect on PSNFL (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) | ||||||
(-j) Minus revaluation of equity assets | ||||||
(h) Net lending | ||||||
of which: | ||||||
(l) Outlays | ||||||
(m) Repayments | ||||||
(i) Net equity investments | ||||||
(n) Effect on PSND (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) |
2.2 Budgetary impacts
FTs can have differing fiscal costs to budgetary impacts. The Treasury will provide advice to Treasury ministers based on both the budgeting and fiscal impacts and so it is important that both are set out.
Financial transaction budgetary impacts | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Year | FY-0 | FY-1 | FY-2 | FY-3 | FY-4 | Extend as needed |
CDEL FT | ||||||
CDEL | ||||||
RDEL | ||||||
o/w ECLs | ||||||
CAME | ||||||
RAME |
3. Risk Management
Investing in financial assets exposes government to downside risk and changes in asset values directly feed through into government’s debt target. This section aims to understand the riskiness of a proposed FT.
3.1 Is it possible to model risk in a (for example) 1 in 10 or 1 in 100 downside scenario? If so, what value do assets retain in this scenario?
3.2 What are the trigger events for this significant downside scenario materialising?
3.3 What are the key upside value drivers in the FT?
3.4 Are there wider factors that may influence expected returns of this FT and if so, what are they?
3.5 What is the exit strategy from the intervention?
4. Classification
FTs will have differing fiscal impacts depending on whether the FT is made to an entity inside or outside the public sector. This section aims to understand the classification considerations for the FT programme.
4.1 Is the FT being made to an organisation classified within the public sector? If yes, please set out how that entity will spend the loan/investment e.g., current spending, capital spending or FTs.
4.2 Will the FT risk the investee being reclassified to the public sector? Are any potential co-investors public sector entities?
5. Delivery
FTs will have different methods of delivery. This section aims to ensure the FT is being delivered most effectively, with the appropriate safeguards and considerations in place.
5.1 Does the organisation delivering the FT have sufficient expertise, capacity, remit, and set-up to manage these financial instruments?
5.2 What are the key operational risks for the organisation that is responsible for its delivery?
5.3 How will the FT be funded? (A public financial institution’s existing capitalisation, departmental ‘subsidy’, or department CDEL FT budget)
5.4 If the FT is being delivered outside of a designated public financial institution, what is the rationale and how will it be delivered effectively?
Annex F: Financial transaction checklist guidance
Overview
This annex provides guidance on how to answer the FT checklist.
Strategic Case Summary
The first section asks organisations to set out what the FT is, the policy rationale and the value for money case, showing why this FT has been put forward amongst other options.
1.1 What policy change is the FT intended to bring about?
- This question asks you to summarise the FT proposed. Having read this, someone unfamiliar with the proposal and policy context should be able to understand what the FT is that you wish to enter.
- Please state if the FT is a loan, an equity investment, or another type of transaction.
1.2 What is the scale and scope of the intervention of the policy?
Please include:
- The notional amount of the FT (cost).
- The number of FTs that are being facilitated – is it a single large FT or many smaller FTs?
- The average size per investment. This should be the average pay-out for each FT, rather than the average pay-out in each financial year.
1.3 What is the expected start and end date of the FT?
- This section asks you to detail the time over which this FT or FT programme is expected to operate. Please make clear the proposed start- and end-date of the FT or FT programme.
- Please provide an explanation for how you have determined the start- and end-date.
- If there is no end-date, this should be made clear and an explanation given (i.e., the rationale for holding an asset in perpetuity).
1.4 Who is the ‘economic’ beneficiary of the FT?
- Please state the organisation or individuals that will be receiving the finance – to whom will the payment be made?
1.5 What are the specific objectives of this intervention and how does it support ministerial priorities?
- This section asks you to describe what the intention of the policy is.
- There should be consideration of wider policies already active in this area that could be aiming to achieve similar policy objectives.
1.6 Please set out a clear articulation of the market failure requiring intervention. Why has the private sector not provided this product?
- This section requires you to clearly state what market failure(s) are present to require a government FT intervention to resolve it.
- Please state why the private sector have not been able to address this and why government support is needed.
1.7 Why is an FT the best policy lever to address this market failure compared to alternative interventions or a do-nothing option?
- This question asks you to provide a clear summary of why an FT is the best option to address the market failure stated above.
- Please also be clear why other policy levers have been ruled out to arrive at this conclusion.
1.8 Will the FT be concessional, concessional but cover the government’s cost of borrowing, or be loss-making and why is this pricing suitable?
- This question asks you to state whether the FT will be priced at a commercial rate or be issued on concessional terms.
- It also asks you to state whether the proposed FT will be loss-making, with reference to the government’s cost of borrowing.
- Please set out how you determined that this pricing was suitable, including expert advice such as a public financial institution or UKGI.
1.9 Does this comply with the Subsidy Control Act?
- Please state if the FT complies with the Subsidy Control Act and who has signed off that it is compliant.
- If it does not comply, please explain what steps are being taken to ensure it is compliant.
Financial costs
2.1 Fiscal impacts
Please complete the table summarising the fiscal impacts of this FT. Please set out your central expectation for returns and valuations such that they are equally likely to be an overestimate as an underestimate.
-
The table asks for key metrics the Treasury will need to assess the financial implications of the proposed FT (Current Budget Balance, Public Sector Net Borrowing, Public Sector Net Financial Liabilities and Public Sector Net Debt). The receipts and expenditure figures will be presented on an accruals basis, in line with fiscal treatment.
-
Given the nature of FTs it is possible that figures in this table will be estimates with a reasonable degree of uncertainty. Please provide your best estimate, at a minimum offering an indication of the quantum for the categories provided below.
-
It is acceptable to apply professional judgement when completing this table if you state and explain above the table who you have consulted. Professional judgement could include consulting domain experts, analytical experts, public financial institutions or UKGI.
-
If you have an alternative method to calculate the key metrics in the table below, please do so but provide an explanation above the table of why you have done so and how.
Financial transaction costing table | |
---|---|
Year | FY-0 refers to the current financial year, FY-1 to the first year of the rolling OBR forecast. The table should be extended to cover all financial years over which the FT has a fiscal impact. |
(a) Receipts | This row is an input. It should be negative if income is received. Does the policy involve earning interest or dividends? Record here if so. |
(b) Expenditure | This row is a formula (b) = (c) + (d) + (e). For each column, please add the current (operating costs and guarantee fee income) and capital (loan write-offs and guarantee calls) expenditure, as well as debt interest indirect effects, to provide this row. |
of which: | |
(c) Current (operating costs and guarantee fee income, excluding debt interest) | This row is an input. It should be positive but also inclusive of guarantee fee income (negative). Does the policy require any new DEL or AME funding? |
(d) Capital (loan write-offs and guarantee calls) | This row is an input. It should be positive. For loans or guarantees, record any spending on write offs or guarantee calls here. Write offs should be recorded at the point of crystallisation not impairment. |
(e) Debt interest costs (indirect effects) | This row is the average market-implied gilt yield multiplied by (h) or (j) as appropriate. It should be positive. Please use the nominal gilt yield curve in your calculations. |
(f) Effect on CBB (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) | This row is a formula (f) = (a) + (c) + (e). |
(g) Effect on PSNB (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) | This row is a formula (g) = (a) + (b). |
(h) Debt securities issued to finance lending | This row is an input. This is the value of debt issued to fund lending – usually the same amount as the cash amount lent unless the loans are intended to be funded by asset sales. |
(-h) Loan assets | This row is a formula (h) x –1 unless asset purchases are financed without issuing additional debt, e.g., by asset sales. It captures loan assets acquired that are netted off in PSNFL. |
(i) Debt securities issued to finance equity investments | This row is an input. This is the value of debt issued to fund equity investments, which is usually the same amount as the cash amount invested. |
(-i) Equity assets | This row is a formula (i) x –1 unless asset purchases are financed without issuing additional debt, e.g., by asset sales. It captures equity assets acquired that are netted off in PSNFL. |
(j) Revaluation of equity assets (rise in value = negative) | This row is an input. It measures the change in the value of equity assets over time. If the value of equity rises it reduces PSNFL, so should be recorded as an exchequer gain (i.e., be negative). |
(k) Effect on PSNFL (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) | This row is a formula (k) = (g) + (j). For each column, please add the effect on PSNB to the revaluation of equity assets to provide this row. |
(-j) Minus revaluation of equity assets | This row is a formula. (j) x -1. This strips out valuation changes that are only reflected in PSND on the sale of equity assets (i.e., when cash changes hands). |
(h) Net lending | This row is a formula (h) = (l) + (m). For each column, please subtract the outlays from the repayments. |
of which: | |
(l) Outlays | This row is an input. It should be positive as it is an exchequer loss. |
(m) Repayments | This row is an input. It should be negative as it is an exchequer gain. |
(i) Net equity investments (assets acquired minus assets sold) | This row is an input. When assets are sold the cash raised is netted off against debt securities issued to finance equity assets. Use the cash values of the acquisition of the equity asset and the sale of the equity asset |
(n) Effect on PSND (negative = reduction, i.e., benefit) | This row is a formula (n) = (g) - (j) + (h) + (i). It is the total effect on PSND, i.e., the PSNB effect plus the financial transaction effect of the measure. |
2.2 Budgeting impacts
FTs can have differing fiscal costs to their costs in budgets. HMT will provide advice to HMT ministers on both budgeting and fiscal costs and so it is important that both are set out when bidding for FTs.
- Please input the budgeting implications for the FT into the table, following Consolidated Budgeting Guidance rules.
Risk Management
Investing in financial assets exposes government both to upside benefits and downside risk. Changes in asset valuation will directly feed through into the government’s debt target. This section aims to understand the riskiness of the proposed FT and the fiscal risk created.
3.1 Is it possible to model risk in a (for example) 1 in 10 or 1 in 100 downside scenario? If so, what value do assets retain in this scenario?
3.2 What are the trigger events for this significant downside scenario materialising?
- Please set out the chain or chains of events that would cause a loan or equity investment to fail to meet its expected returns.
3.3 What are the key upside value drivers in the FT?
- This question asks you to set out and explain what factors you think will contribute towards driving a positive return on the investment.
3.4 Are there any wider factors that may influence the expected returns of this FT and if so, what are they?
- If there are any additional factors, outside those listed above, with the potential to affect the returns of the FT, please explain these.
3.5 What is the exit strategy? (For example, term to repayment of a loan or sale of equity holding)
- Each investment should have a clear exit strategy before it is entered and if there is no strategy there should be an explanation of why that is the case (i.e., a plan to hold the asset in perpetuity).
- If the exit strategy is likely to change or there are potentially multiple exit strategies, please include in this section.
Classification
Financial Transactions will have different impacts on headline public sector fiscal metrics depending on whether the FT is made to an entity inside or outside the public sector. This section aims to understand the classification risks associated with the FT programme.
4.1 Is the FT being made to an organisation classified within the public sector? If yes, please set out how that entity will spend the loan/investment e.g., current spending, capital spending or FTs.
4.2 Will the FT risk the investee being reclassified to the public sector? Are any potential co-investors public sector entities?
-
Could the FT be viewed to give the public sector control over the investee? The ONS will automatically view any majority equity ownership as control and would consider any conditions attached to minority equity stakes, as well as debt investments, to see if they could give rise to control for the public sector over the investee.
-
When assessing this risk, the aggregate public sector investment in an investee should be considered (i.e., any co-investment by another public corporation, central government body or local government body should be included when assessing whether control exists).
Delivery
FTs will have different methods of delivery. This section aims to ensure the FT is being delivered most effectively with the appropriate safeguards and considerations in place.
5.1 Does the organisation delivering the FT have sufficient expertise, capacity, remit, and set-up to manage these financial instruments?
- This question asks the department to provide a summary explaining how the organisation delivering the FT can do so.
- If a public financial institution is due to deliver the FT, there should be a description of how their mandate (legislated objectives) relates to the policy area, as well as their constitutional set up (e.g., financial framework) makes them a good fit for delivery.
- If the intended delivery organisation does not currently have the capability or capacity to deliver the FT, please discuss this with your Treasury spending team.
5.2 What are the key operational risks for the organisation that is responsible for its delivery?
- This question asks you to summarise the risks that are present within the delivery organisation that may impact their ability to deliver the FT and operate in line with this control framework.
- If there are issues identified, please set out what is being done to address or mitigate them.
5.3 How will the FT be funded?
- Please set out whether the FT will be funded either by a public financial institution’s existing capitalisation, a ‘subsidy’ from a department, or via a department’s CDEL FT budget.
5.4 If the FT will be delivered outside of a public financial institution, what is the rationale and how will it be delivered effectively?
- This question asks departments to explain in detail why a public financial institution cannot deliver this FT.
- Please explain the rationale for delivering via another organisation and how will the department ensure it is delivered effectively in line with the principles of this framework.
-
Definitions follow the National Accounts, set out in the ‘System of National Accounts, 2008’ and ‘Eurostat’. ↩
-
Managing Public Money, HM Treasury, 2023; Consolidated budgeting guidance, HM Treasury, 2025. ↩
-
The Green Book , HM Treasury, May 2024 ↩
-
Statement of Funding Policy, HM Treasury, October 2021 ↩
-
Definitions follow the National Accounts, set out in the System of National Accounts and Eurostat. ↩
-
Contingent Liability Approval Framework, HM Treasury, April 2023 ↩
-
Economic & Labour Market Review, Volume 3, Issue 7, ‘The public sector balance sheet’, July 2009 ↩
-
Covid-19 Bounce Back Loan Scheme , British Business Bank ↩
-
Direct Lending Facility, UK Export Finance ↩
-
Innovation loans, UK Research & Innovation ↩
-
UK subsidy control regime: statutory guidance - GOV.UK, Department for Business and Trade, January 2025 ↩
-
Orange Book, HM Treasury, 2013 ↩
-
Implementation of the Basel 3.1 standards: Credit risk – standardised approach, Bank of England, November 2022 ↩
-
CRE20 - Standardised approach: individual exposures – N.B. the table included is aimed to be illustrative. ↩
-
The PRA’s methodologies for setting pillar 2 capital, Bank of England, July 2021 ↩
-
The PRA’s methodologies for setting pillar 2 capital - interest rate risk , Bank of England, September 2024 ↩
-
The Internal Capital Adequacy Assessment Process (ICAAP) , Bank of England, May 2023 ↩
-
Contingent Liability Approval Framework, April 2023 ↩